To quantify an answer to the title question we have to understand both the scope of the defaults/delinquencies involved and the likely behavior of the consumers caught up in those situations.
Scope of Defaults and Delinquencies The best data that we have seen to-date on the scope of delinquency issues is published quarterly by the Mortgage Bankers Association (“MBA”). Their latest report was published on November 18, 2010 and covers the third quarter of 2010. In that data release the overall (non-seasonally adjusted) delinquency rate for owner occupied one-to-four-unit residential properties was reported to be 9.39%. According to their press release that specific “delinquency rate includes loans that are at least one payment past due but does not include loans in the process of foreclosure.” The MBA report then separately addresses the additional percentage of loans that had progressed to “the foreclosure process,” reporting that the number was 4.39%. This would bring the total number of non-mortgage-paying owner-occupiers (delinquencies through foreclosures) to about 13.8%. Economic Impact of Defaults and Delinquencies To estimate the economic impact of the defaulting homeowners, we can do some back-of-the-envelope calculations using data from the U.S. Census Bureau and the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. In the latest Census/HUD publication of the “American Housing Survey” (covering the fall of 2009), there were about 76.4 million owner-occupied housing units, of which 50.3 million had at least one mortgage still active. If the 13.8% total delinquency rate is applied to the number of currently active mortgages, roughly 6.9 million homeowners have missed at least one mortgage payment. Since some of these instances might not be in irretrievable default (or involve multiple mortgages on the same property), we chose to use a more conservative 5 million for the purposes of our calculations. From another Census Bureau table we can make educated estimates of the total cash-flow represented by the 5 million delinquencies. From the table showing the distribution of mortgages by payment value, we have extrapolated the likely average monthly principal, interest and escrow (taxes and insurance) (“PITI”) payments for the delinquent mortgages. To do this we have made a two key assumptions: 1) that the owner/occupants have continued to pay utilities during their “rent free” stage; and 2) that the greater portion of defaulters had originated their loans in the past decade (and therefore had the highest payment schedules and the greatest likelihood of being upside-down). Using these assumptions, we have concluded that the the average cash-flow freed up by defaulters is about $1,500 per month. Assuming 5 million defaulters missing $1,500 per month in mortgage PITI payments, the total annualized free cash-flow is something like $90 billion — about 8% of total annual consumer spending on discretionary durable goods. Should you feel more comfortable using average monthly payments that are higher or lower than the $1,500 that we used, simply scale the $90 billion accordingly. Behavioral Patterns Clearly not all of the $90 billion will end up as consumer spending. Presumably many defaulters have maxed-out their credit cards before starting the default process — although there is some evidence that at least some have treated credit cards as the more senior (or at least less hopeless) obligation. If the average household credit card debt is in the $16,000 range, for our back-of-the-envelope calculation we might assume that those in default average about twice that total — which with the recently increased minimum payment levels will eat up about half of the freed-up cash-flow. We also understand that the defaulters will go through several stages (psychological as well as legal and financial) during the entire process. At first they may be in denial and think that they will be able to clear things up in a month or two. During that time we expect no changes in spending behavior, with any free cash ending up in a cookie jar with the intent of eventually correcting the arrears. After several months, the hopelessness of the situation may become more evident, and with that resignation there may be a real sense of liberation. Between then and the point of imminent eviction we might expect the free-cash to start to come out of the cookie jar as a self-medicated analgesic for their financial ills. If the foreclosure process gets extended through legal maneuvers, court mandated moratoriums or new claim documentation standards, the defaulters may sense a true unexpected windfall — hitting the “free rent” lottery and loosening their spending constraints. Some law practices have moved into this niche, indicating that aggressive defense tactics can extend the foreclosure process to as much as 18 months. Any such delays will simply swell the number of mortgages “in the foreclosure process” and the $90 billion commensurately. Furthermore, once the default process begins most of the defaulters will see their credit card limits impaired. As a consequence of this there will be an increase in the percentage of their consumer transactions that are conducted in cash, checks, debit cards or equivalents. This change will reduce the share of their purchases that are made on-line — as will any uncertainty about future shipping addresses. Obviously the broad stroke of behavior outlined above won’t apply to everyone. For young people ultimately headed back to Mom and Dad’s basement, the future is also largely rent-free and a larger portion of the improved cash flow could be spent. Affluent “strategic defaulters” may also not be materially hampered by crippling revolving credit — again making the improved cash flow available for spending. Some defaulters may chose to apply a vast majority of the new found cash to their credit card balances. Others may abandon the property long before the eviction notices even get posted. Still others may still be barely making ends meet even during the “rent free” period. The Bottom Line If we assume that our defaulters were able to cover most other non-discretionary budget items before the default process began, we can then also assume that most of the cash leaving the cookie jar will end up as discretionary durable goods. If we further assume that somewhere between one-quarter to one-half of the $90 billion actually ends up in consumer spending, we might expect to see discretionary durable goods gaining 2% to 4% annualized at the expense of the mortgage bankers. This may be a partial explanation for the observation that U.S. consumers have recently managed to increase their spending even as real incomes remained nearly stagnant. We also believe that the majority of the increased spending will occur at brick-and-mortar retail establishments. The reasons for this include the defaulter’s impaired credit, a more transient lifestyle, shorter term paycheck-to-paycheck financial cycles, and the simplified budgeting afforded by an all-cash spending environment. Additionally, brick-and-mortar retailers provide relatively simple on-premise ways to facilitate a paycheck-to-paycheck (or unemployment-check-to-unemployment-check, food-stamp to food-stamp) lifestyle. All of which plausibly translates into a market share shift from on-line merchants to more traditional retailers located in the defaulter’s home community. Defaults and the CPI If consumers are indeed decreasing their costs for shelter by $90 billion dollars per year, we might well expect to see a corresponding deflationary impact on the cost of living. Specifically, we might ask how mortgage delinquencies (or, indeed, the drop in home prices) get reflected in the “Owner’s Equivalent Rent of Primary Residence” (“OER”) component of the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ (“BLS”) Consumer Price Index (“CPI”)? The answer? Not at all. The OER component of the CPI actually comes from a simple question asked in the household survey: “If someone were to rent your home today, how much do you think it would rent for monthly, unfurnished and without utilities?” In other words, consumers are simply asked to guess how much they could charge for rent for their home if it was put on the rental market. We have concerns about how knowledgeable most consumers are about the current house rental market in their locale, especially if they have not dealt with that market over the past decade or so. Nevertheless, that remains the source of the OER component of the CPI. It would at least be more credible to have that question answered by rental market surveys. Given something like 19 million homes vacant one might also expect those home rental costs to be dropping in concert with home prices, instead of remaining essentially flat as the OER has done recently. Unfortunately, such expectations fail to recognize that banks would rather auction than rent — despite the impaired asset “price discovery” inherent during an auction. While it may seem reasonable to use a home rental equivalent as a proxy for home ownership costs in the CPI, the current data collection process is flawed to the point of being dangerously misleading. Much better would be some process that utilizes the same mortgage weightings that we performed while trying to quantify the impact of the delinquencies. If that process was properly done it would capture changes in the costs of financing as well as recognizing that a growing portion of our population has been aging into paid-off mortgages (now some 25 million households), causing the actual monthly out-of-pocket costs for at least the “Baby-Boomer” demographic to be declining. For all of these reasons we’re not sure that any form of surveyed “rental equivalence” is an accurate way to capture the true cost of home ownership for the vast majority of owner-occupied residences. Our DataOur data shows broad swings over the past year in the level of consumers contemplating “strategic defaults”, and the most recent data shows that the levels have fallen off sharply from peaks reached early in 4Q-2010: We continue to regard a couple of our other sub-sector charts as particularly telling indicators of the comfort that our shoppers have with the prospect of taking on new debt. The first of these is simply new applications for loans for newly acquired residential properties: In the above chart the day-by-day courses of the 2008 and 2010 contractions in our Daily Growth Index are plotted in a superimposed manner with the plots aligned on the left margin at the first day during each event that our Daily Growth Index went negative. The plots then progress day-by-day to the right, tracing out the changes in the daily rate of contraction in consumer demand for the two events. The 2010 contraction event is now more than a year old, dating back to January 15, 2010. Although the chart clearly bottomed at about 9 months into the contraction (at roughly 270 days), the rise since that bottom has been neither steady nor substantial. In fact, there is no way to forecast when the indicated contraction of on-line consumer demand for discretionary durable goods will end based solely on the recent course of the blue line. Our bottom line remains that any “recovery” currently in progress is probably far more fragile than is commonly assumed. We also believe that our data confirms what most people on “Main Street” already know: that during the “Great Recession” and its postlude, neither the pains nor subsequent gains were fully shared across the broad cross-section of Americans. This recession may have ended for Mr. Bernanke, Mr. Geithner and their colleagues at Goldman Sachs, but it has not yet ended for the on-line “Main Street” consumers that we track on a daily basis. |
Related Articles
Advance GDP Estimate for 4Q/2010 has Disturbing Undercurrents by Rick Davis
Consumer Credit Expands in December 2010 by Steven Hansen
Consumer Contraction May be Bottoming by Rick Davis
Michigan Consumer Sentiment Index: January Ends Lower than December by Doug Short
The American Housing Survey is funded and directed by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. It is conducted by the Census Bureau under contract with HUD. Thus, it should be called a HUD survey, or a joint HUD/Census survey.
For AHS microdata files, please see http://www.huduser.org/portal/datasets/ahs.html
davanden – – –
I have changed the subject sentences to read:
To estimate the economic impact of the defaulting homeowners, we can do some back-of-the-envelope calculations using data from the U.S. Census Bureau and the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. In the latest Census/HUD publication of the “American Housing Survey” (covering the fall of 2009), there were about 76.4 million owner-occupied housing units, of which 50.3 million had at least one mortgage still active.
Note: Links are not active here – please see the text at the beginning of the article section “Economic Impact of Defaults and Delinquencies”