from the International Monetary Fund
— this post authored by M. Ayhan Kose, Franziska Ohnsorge, and Naotaka Sugawara
Over the past decade, the implications of recent technological innovations for future growth have become a subject of lively debate. Some claim that, in the coming decades, the global economy will enjoy a surge in economic growth driven by improvements in productivity thanks to new technologies (Brynjolfsson and McAfee 2014; Mokyr 2018). Others caution that future growth could stall, or even decline, because new technologies will likely have a diminishing marginal impact on productivity and structural challenges associated with aging and sluggish investment growth will cast a pall on prospects (Gordon 2016).
It is difficult, if not impossible, to undertake a credible quantitative analysis of the aggregate impact of new technologies on growth prospects. However, long-term growth forecasts could provide a small window into this debate. These forecasts could be expected to improve over time as new technologies, such as machine learning, cloud computing, robotics, and smartphones, spread. But is this borne out by the data? In our study, we examine how long-range forecasts have evolved during a period of rapid technological change in order to gauge what this might mean for future growth (Kose, Ohnsorge, and Sugawara, forthcoming).
Our analysis is based on forecasts published by Consensus Economics, a firm that surveys professional forecasters several times a year to generate its long-term annual growth projections – the average forecast for 6 – 10 years ahead. Forecasts by Consensus Economics reflect the perspectives of many institutions that use a wide range of methodologies, so they tend to stand up to potential uncertainty better than projections produced by a single entity. Our sample includes long-term forecasts over 1998 – 2018 for 20 advanced economies and 18 emerging market and developing economies that constitute roughly 90 percent of global GDP.
Increasingly pessimistic
Long-term global growth forecasts made a decade earlier exceeded actual outcomes in every year of the 2008 – 18 period except 2010 (see Chart 2). The same was true for the majority of individual country forecasts. And even in 2010, forecasts were overly optimistic for about half of advanced economies and a quarter of other economies.
The analysis here covers mainly the crisis and postcrisis periods that witnessed an unusual series of negative growth shocks, but the optimism bias of forecasts has been widely documented. Time and again, growth forecasts have proved overly optimistic relative to outcomes (Ho and Mauro 2015). Moreover, the degree of optimism tends to increase as the time horizon gets longer. On average, long-range forecasts overshot actual growth by 1.2 percentage points, and three-year-ahead forecasts overestimated growth by 0.7 percentage point over the period until 2018.
Since long-term growth expectations presumably abstract from cyclical effects, they should reflect forecasters’ judgment about potential growth. But do they? Long-term forecasts for global growth often exceed the estimates of global potential growth over the decade that follows. These observations suggest that long-term growth forecasts have remained optimistic relative to eventual outcomes and potential growth estimates, despite becoming more pessimistic during the postcrisis period.
Long-term forecasts tend to improve during periods of sustained strong output growth. In other words, growth expectations generally rise if productivity, employment, and investment growth increase for a prolonged period.
Between hope and despondency
For now, forecasters appear to hold a cautious view of the growth boost from new technologies over the next decade, more in line with the technology pessimists than the technology optimists. Instead of a technology-driven productivity boost, growth is expected to slide further. This pessimism could reflect an awareness that weak productivity growth, increasingly unfavorable demographic trends, and subdued investment prospects are likely to weigh on global potential growth in the coming years.
There could, of course, be other explanations for increasingly pessimistic forecasts in an era of rapid technological change. First, forecasters may benchmark their forecasts against recent low productivity growth – but this indicator may be underestimated because of measurement error. Nobel Prize – winning economist Robert Solow nicely summarized the issue of measurement by saying, “You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics.”
Second, forecasters may be unable to project the impact of major technological changes on productivity and output growth because these types of changes, such as the mass use of electricity and cars, are rare and, when they happen, their impact on aggregate growth and productivity is felt only gradually. Moreover, a quantitative study of their implications for growth prospects requires improvements in econometric tools and data that are not available at the moment.
Both explanations attribute the decline largely to a lack of good information.
A third explanation is less benign: structural headwinds from adverse demographic trends, slowing investment growth, and stagnating productivity as a result of existing widely used technologies may reduce growth prospects to such an extent that even large productivity gains from new technologies will not be able to deliver strong long-term growth. This could mean that new technologies are still not mature enough to be widely used for general business purposes, and that their diffusion requires long and uncertain lags. It could also reflect obstacles to firms’ adoption of new technologies, such as financing constraints and limited worker skills.
These explanations aside, if past performance is any guide, even these increasingly pessimistic long-term forecasts may eventually turn out to be optimistic as growth – yet again, as in the past two decades – disappoints. One message is clear: a hopeful outlook about future global growth depends on a significant pickup in measured productivity to offset the structural impediments confronting the world economy.
Rapid technological change may eventually bring a new era of global prosperity. However, rather than wait for that new era to arrive, policymakers must act now with measures to enhance their economies’ potential growth. In the spirit of US President Dwight D. Eisenhower’s dictum “Plans are worthless, but planning is everything,” governments should prepare for the worst, even if the actual impact of new technologies is still unknown. This implies an urgent need to press ahead with initiatives to accelerate the realization of new technologies’ growth benefits. These initiatives include raising investment in human capital and expanding infrastructure investment to facilitate the use of new technologies, as well as improving institutions and regulations to meet the needs of technological change.
Source
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2019/03/technology-and-long-term-growth-forecasts-kose.htm
Disclaimer
Opinions expressed in articles and other materials are those of the authors; they do not necessarily reflect IMF policy.
About the Authors
M. AYHAN KOSE is director of the World Bank’s Development Prospects Group, where FRANZISKA OHNSORGE is manager and NAOTAKA SUGAWARA is senior economist.
References:
Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Andrew McAfee. 2014. The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies . New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
Gordon, Robert J. 2016. The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War . Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.
Ho, Giang, and Paolo Mauro. 2015. “Prognosis: Rosy.” Finance & Development 52 (1): 40 – 43.
Kose, M. Ayhan, Franziska Ohnsorge, and Naotaka Sugawara. Forthcoming. “Global Growth Next Decade: Optimistic Expectations, Disappointing Outcomes.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Mokyr, Joel. 2018. “Building Taller Ladders.” Finance & Development 55 (2): 32 – 35.
PHOTO: ISTOCK/MONSITJ