>

The Great Debate© – Can Austerity Produce Recovery from The Great Recession?

Guest Author:  Dean Baker is an economist and Co-Director of the Center for Economic and Policy Research, in Washington, D.C. – Full Bio here.

Framing the debate:  There is a school of thought that has argued the recovery can be aided by fiscal austerity embodied in lower taxes accompanied by even larger reductions in government spending.  A comprehensive research paper from Goldman Sachs earlier this year presented such a well researched argument.  The paper, Global Economics Paper No. 195, by Ben Broadbent and Kevin Daly, was entitled “Limiting the Fall-Out from Fiscal Adjustment“.  The other side of the argument, equally well researched, was presented last week by Dean Baker. 

 
The Myth of Expansionary Fiscal Austerity

by Dean Baker 

Introduction

Recently governments, economists, and international financial institutions have been debating the merits of further fiscal stimulus to combat the Great Recession versus fiscal austerity or “adjustment” – that is, higher taxes and/or lower government spending – to combat budget deficits.  Some supporters of austerity have gone as far as arguing that fiscal adjustment could restore economic growth. These analyses are being touted to oppose increased stimulus to boost the economy. This paper examines the arguments for austerity and demonstrates that current economic conditions in the United States do not support the case for fiscal adjustment.

 The Effects of the Great Recession

 The Great Recession has led to the longest sustained period of high unemployment in the post-war era. The unemployment rate in the United States was 9.6 percent in August, 4.6 percentage points above the Congressional Budget Office’s (CBO) estimate of the rate we would have if the economy were now operating at its full capacity and 5.1 percentage points above the low point hit in 2007 before the recession.1  This large unemployment gap would seem to argue for aggressive fiscal and monetary stimulus.  CBO also calculates that the gap between potential GDP and actual GDP will be $730 billion in 2010. This is equal to almost $2,400 in wasted output per person. By 2014, when CBO projects that the economy will again be close to normal levels of unemployment, the economy is projected to have lost a total of $3.4 trillion in output due to the downturn, more than $11,000 per person, as shown in Figures 1a and 1b.  Losses of this magnitude swamp the damage done by even the worst policy mistakes of the last half-century.  The losses from the recession also vastly exceed the cost of any of the government programs that have proven controversial in recent years, as shown in Figure 2.

It is worth noting that even these projections may prove overly optimistic. CBO projected that the unemployment rate would average 9.5 percent for 2010. Thus far it has averaged 9.7 percent. With the economy creating few, if any, jobs, the unemployment rate is likely to rise by the end of the year.  This means that the gaps in output for both 2010 and 2011 are likely to be considerably higher than CBO had projected.

The situation is made even worse by the fact that these losses are not evenly shared. High rates of unemployment create anxiety among tens of millions of employed but vulnerable workers. They also put downward pressure on the wages of workers who most fear unemployment, which are disproportionately workers without college degrees.

 However, the unemployed and under-employed bear the bulk of the loss that results from the economy operating far below its potential level of output.  These workers have, by far, seen the sharpest decline in income and are in the most precarious financial situation. They have suffered the greatest losses from the Great Recession.  By contrast, corporate profits have completely recovered from the downturn. In the 2nd quarter of 2010, the broadest measure of corporate profits, net operating surplus, stood at $1,570 billion.  This is $104 billion, or more than 7.0 percent, above the pre-recession peak reached in the 2nd quarter of 2007, as shown in Figure 3.  The recovery of profits suggests that corporations, or more specifically their major shareholders and top executives, are no longer feeling the pain of the downturn.  They have managed to adjust to an environment of lower output by increasing their profit margins. Even though their revenues may still be below pre-recession levels, by increasing the profit share of corporate income they have been able to shield themselves from the effects of continuing economic weakness.

  This background is worth noting in assessing the case for stimulus. While restoring the economy to its potential level of output will offer large gains to those who are unemployed or at substantial risk of unemployment, those who derive their income from owning capital or running large corporations will have less obvious benefits from a return to full employment.

The Logic of an Expansionary Fiscal Adjustment

 Proponents of fiscal stimulus see the direct effects of the stimulus as fostering growth. Government spending, for example on infrastructure or education, directly employs people and also provides paychecks that will mostly be spent by the workers hired, creating additional demand and employment. Transfer payments like unemployment benefits or tax cuts also put money into people’s pockets, much of which will typically be spent, thereby creating demand and jobs.

 By contrast, advocates of fiscal adjustment, in the form of higher taxes and/or lower government spending, rely on the indirect effect of these policies to increase growth. The argument is that fiscal adjustment will reduce the government’s demand on the economy’s resources, thereby allowing the private sector to make better use of these resources. In principle, this shift to private sector spending comes about through lower interest rates, which both fosters domestic investment and leads to a lower-valued currency that supports improvements in the trade balance.  The decline in the value of the currency makes the adjusting country’s goods more competitive internationally.  With a lower-valued currency, imports are more expensive relative to domestically produced goods, which should lead to a substitution of domestically produced items for imports. At the same time, a lower-valued currency makes the adjusting country’s exports cheaper for its trading partners. This should lead them to purchase more of the country’s exports. Reducing imports and increasing exports can be an important channel for growth, especially for a country that is heavily involved in international trade.

 Lower interest rates should also boost domestic investment and consumption. Lower interest rates make it relatively cheaper for firms to borrow money to finance investment in plants and equipment, research and development, or marketing new lines of products. Lower interest rates tend to promote consumption both by making saving relatively less attractive, and also by freeing up money for consumption by allowing consumers to refinance debt at lower interest rates.  This is most notable with mortgages, which can typically be refinanced when interest rates fall. This frees up money from debt payments for other forms of consumption. (While the drop in interest rates reduces the money received by investors, they typically will spend a smaller share of their income than homeowners, so the redistribution from creditors to debtors generally leads to more consumption.)

These routes to increased demand, through lower interest rates, provide clear mechanisms through which a fiscal adjustment can be expansionary.  If the increase in demand from an improved trade position, combined with increased investment and consumption, exceeds the falloff in demand that results from a combination of tax increases and spending cuts, then the fiscal adjustment can be expansionary. Whether in practice it is expansionary depends on the relative size of these effects. Of course, lower interest rates are a key part of the story. If interest rates do not fall as a result of the adjustment, then there is no reason to expect any boost through either the investment or the trade channels.

 The Goldman Sachs Case for Expansionary Adjustments

 There has been a recent series of papers arguing for the growth benefits from fiscal adjustments.  The most prominent proponent of this position, Harvard University economist Alberto Alesina, has written papers over the last two decades purportedly showing that fiscal adjustments can be expansionary even in the short run.2  This work has been widely cited by those who have argued for fiscal austerity even in the context of the sharp downturn that the world economy is now experiencing.

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) recently examined the argument advanced by Alesina and found that adjustments are, in contrast, contractionary in the short run.3 The fiscal adjustments identified by the IMF differed somewhat from the ones identified by Alesina, in part because the IMF focused on changes in deficits that were directly driven by policy. While Alesina did use cyclically adjusted measures of budget deficits, a cyclical adjustment will not always accurately distinguish between changes that were endogenous and changes that were policy-driven.4   When the IMF focused exclusively on policy-driven fiscal adjustments it got results that were consistent with standard Keynesian analysis. In the short run, fiscal adjustment is contractionary, with cuts in spending being more contractionary than increases in taxes. This is consistent with both  the theoretical view that spending will more directly impact the economy than taxes and also a large amount of research that has found higher multipliers for changes in spending than changes in taxes.5

In the same vein as the Alesina work, Goldman Sachs recently produced an analysis that purports to show that fiscal adjustment can be expansionary in the short run and that adjustments that focus on cuts in spending are most likely to promote growth.6  This paper is worth examining because it provides some insight into the logic of this argument and why it is completely inappropriate for the United States in its current economic situation.  This paper, by Broadbent and Daly, identifies 44 instances of large fiscal adjustments over the last 35 years in OECD countries. Of these 44 adjustments, it identifies 11 cases of fiscal adjustment that were accomplished primarily through cuts in spending. The study argues that these expansions were considerably more robust than the expansions following tax adjustments. The paper argues that the expenditure-driven fiscal adjustments led to sharply lower bond yields and strong surges in equity prices. The authors suggest this led to strong growth in investment, which helped fuel growth rates well in excess of the OECD average in the 3-5 years following the adjustment. 

 While the Broadbent and Daly study may provide useful insights on the potential for fiscal adjustments to boost growth, its relevance to the current situation in the United States is questionable. The vast majority of instances of fiscal adjustment took place during periods when economies were near or above potential GDP. In only 6 of the 29 fiscal adjustments that were tax driven was the gap between potential and actual GDP even as large as one percentage point. In only two instances, Netherlands (1983) and Norway (2004-06), were the gaps more than two percentage points of GDP, as shown in Figure 4. By comparison, the output gap in the United States is more than five percentage points of GDP in 2010, according to the Congressional Budget Office.

 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2010/01/weodata/index.aspx

 The story is a bit different with the expenditure-driven adjustments. In five of the ten adjustments for which there is data, the output gap was more than one percentage point of GDP at the beginning of the adjustment. In four of these five cases the gap was more than two percentage points of GDP, as shown in Figure 5. These four cases were Finland (1996-2000), Netherlands (1996), Norway (1994-95), and Sweden (1994-98). However, in none of these cases was an economy as far below its potential as the United States economy in 2010. The biggest output gap among this group was the 3.7 percentage point gap in Sweden at the start of its adjustment. That is still 1.5 percentage points smaller than the gap in the United States.

Reviewing the cases of fiscal adjustment identified by Broadbent and Daly, several points become evident: 

  • First, as the paper notes, expenditure adjustments are relatively rare. While the paper argues that expenditure adjustments are clearly preferable in the sense of producing better growth outcomes, it identifies almost three times as many tax adjustments as expenditure adjustments. With just 11 spending adjustments in more than 600 country/year observations, expenditure adjustments are clearly not very common. The paper argues that expenditure adjustments have essentially only come about when driven by crises of confidence in which the financial markets were no longer willing to lend to these countries.
  •  The second point is that the cases of adjustment in countries that were substantially below full employment were heavily concentrated in a narrow group of countries during a narrow time period.  Three Nordic countries (Finland, Norway and Sweden) account for four of the six cases where the fiscal adjustments took place when the country was at least two percentage points below potential GDP.  The Netherlands accounted for the other two instances.  Four of these six adjustments took place in the mid-1990s, a period of robust growth in most of the world. The other two instances were in Netherlands in 1983 and Norway 2004-2006, both also periods in which the world economy was seeing healthy growth.
  •  The other noteworthy factor about the four countries that have successfully grown through a period of fiscal adjustment, even when they were starting from a point well below potential output, is that these are all relatively small countries that are heavily involved in international trade.  The trade share of GDP in all four of these countries was at least twice the share in the United States in 2008, before trade collapsed as a result of the downturn, as shown in Figure 6. The trade share of Netherlands’ economy is more than three times as large as that of the United States.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/824333188522 .

 This is important for two reasons. First, insofar as trade is driving GDP, it will not be negatively impacted by a fiscal adjustment. The demand from outside of the country will not be reduced by a country’s decision to raise taxes or cut spending. The second reason it is important is that the fiscal adjustment can actually boost trade. A lower deficit can lead to a decline in interest rates, which can in turn be expected to lead to a lower value for the country’s currency relative to that of its trading partners.

 This raises the final important difference between the situation of the Broadbent and Daly success stories and the situation of the United States in 2010. It was possible to have substantial reductions in interest rates in these four countries during their six adjustments because their interest rates were relatively high at the time they began their adjustments. Figure 7 shows the interest rate on 10-year government bonds in the year that Broadbent and Daly list as the starting points for their adjustments. The average interest rate for these countries was 7.2 percent. The lowest was 4.4 percent in Norway in 2004-2006.

By contrast, the interest rate on 10-year Treasury bonds in the third quarter of 2010 has averaged less than 2.6 percent.7  It is not plausible that interest rates could decline much further, even in response to the most extreme fiscal adjustment. The short-term rate in the United States is already at zero so it can literally fall no further, and the long-term rate will surely reach a plateau in excess of zero. After more than a decade of deflation, the interest rate on 10-year bonds in Japan is still 0.9 percent, leaving a real yield that is approximately the same as in the United States. Clearly any further decline in nominal interest rates in the United States will be slow under any circumstances and is likely to result in very little change in real interest rates.

 In contrast, in the countries cited by Broadbent and Daly there was substantial room for declines in interest rates. With less room for movement in current interest rates in the United States, there is considerably less reason to believe that the boost provided by lower interest rates will be able to offset the contractionary impact of a lower deficit.

Furthermore, there is much less a prospect that whatever decline in interest rates does occur will have as much impact as a comparable decline in interest rates would have had for these countries in their periods of adjustment.

 On the trade side, the value of the dollar is likely to be far less sensitive to changes in U.S. interest rates than the value of other currencies. This is due to the fact that dollars are largely held as a reserve currency and a safe asset in uncertain times. This demand will be very unresponsive to changes in interest rates. As a result, whatever drop in interest rates does occur as a result of fiscal adjustment may have no measurable effect on the value of dollar. If the drop in interest rates does not lead to a lower dollar, then it cannot increase net exports.  Since the trade share in the United States is considerably smaller than in these other countries, a change in the trade share of comparable magnitude will have less impact on GDP. In other words, if the U.S. had a 10 percent increase in exports and a 10 percent decline in imports, it would have less than half the impact on its GDP as a comparable change in Norway and less than a third of the impact of a comparable change in trade in the Netherlands.

 The prospect for large improvements in the trade balance are made even worse by the fact that most of the United States’ major trading partners are also suffering from the downturn.  As noted before, four of the six adjustments identified by Broadbent and Daly in countries operating far below potential GDP occurred during the period of robust world growth in the mid-1990s. It is far easier for a country to improve its trade balance when its trade partners are growing rapidly than when they are stagnating.

 In short, there is little reason to believe that a fiscal adjustment will lead to a substantial improvement in the United States’ trade position any time in the near future. This channel for offsetting the contractionary impact of deficit reduction is not very promising.

 The investment channel does not appear much more promising. With interest rates already at historic lows, it seems implausible that whatever further decline may occur as a result of adjustment could have very much impact. In most sectors output remains far below capacity, so firms have little incentive to expand capacity far in advance of demand. This is especially true because the bubble in non-residential real estate led to enormous excess supply in most areas.  Businesses can invest in modernizing equipment, but the impact of further declines in interest rates is likely to be limited.

 There is a large body of research that finds that investment is not very responsive to interest rates.8  Furthermore, the rate of growth of equipment and software investment is already quite rapid, with growth averaging 19.9 percent from third quarter of 2009 to the second quarter of 2010. It does not seem likely that lower interest rates will increase this rate substantially, especially in a context where demand is contracting due to budget cuts.

 There is one final point that is worth emphasizing about the Broadbent and Daly analysis. The paper pulls out public investment from government spending and treats it as a separate variable. The remaining categories of spending are direct transfer payments or current consumption items such as health care or defense. Although the paper does not emphasize this fact, government spending on public investment is consistently shown to have a highly significant and positive impact on growth.  This suggests both that cutting spending on investment categories of the budget (e.g. infrastructure and research and development) would be contractionary, and that increased spending on these areas would be an effective form of stimulus. The implication of this analysis is that even a paper that emphasizes the virtues of lower budget deficits finds that higher deficits that are used to finance investment lead to more rapid growth in the short run.

 Conclusion

 There has been a considerable effort to tout the merits of fiscal austerity as a route to restoring growth. This argument has been put forward in direct opposition to arguments for increased stimulus for boosting the economy. While there may be a case that lower deficits can foster growth under some circumstances, the evidence presented in the Broadbent and Daly paper does not suggest that a movement toward lower deficits in the current economic situation in the United States would be expansionary.

 Very few of the countries in which fiscal austerity was associated with more rapid growth adopted austerity at a time when the economy was far below its potential level of output.  In none of the cases were they are as far below as the United States is today. In all of the cases where there was a substantial output gap, the country was far more engaged in international trade than the United States. Trade provided a source of  demand that cannot have anywhere near as large an impact in the United States at present.

 Finally, all the countries that successfully used austerity to boost growth had much higher interest rates than the United States does at present. This meant that there was substantial room for rates to decline following the imposition of austerity.

 The differences between the United States in 2010 and the countries that have successfully gone the route of fiscal austerity to boost growth are large and are very central to the adjustment process. In short, in the current economic environment, the circumstances do not exist for fiscal austerity in the United States to lead to more rapid growth. While a quick return to normal levels of unemployment may not be important to those who are primarily dependent on profits or run large corporations, for most of the country, it is essential to their well-being.

 Footnotes

 1 Congressional Budget Office. 2010. “The Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2010-2020.” Washington, D.C.:  Congressional Budget Office. Available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/108xx/doc10871/01-26-Outlook.pdf

 2 See Alesina, A. and R. Perotti. 1995. “Fiscal Expansion and Adjustments in OECD Economies.” Economic Policy, 207-247; and Alesina, A., S. Ardagna, and F. Trebbi. 2006. “Who Adjusts and When? The Political Economy of Reform.” IMF Staff Papers V. 53 Special Issue.

 3 International Monetary Fund. 2010. “Will It Hurt? Macroeconomic Effects of Fiscal Consolidation.” Economic Outlook, Chapter 3.

 4 For example, in the late 1990s the budget surplus in the United States increased far more than would have been predicted by a normal cyclical adjustment. This was largely attributable to soaring capital gains tax revenue from the stock bubble.

 5 Arjun Jayadev and Mike Konzcal did a similar analysis of Alesina’s work. See Jayadev, A. and M. Konczal. 2010. “The Boom not the Slump: The Right Time for Austerity.” Roosevelt Institute, available at http://www.rooseveltinstitute.org/sites/all/files/not_the_time_for_austerity.pdf.

 6 Broadbent, B. and K. Daly. 2010. “Limiting the Fall-Out from Fiscal Adjustments.” Goldman Sachs Global Economics, Global Economics Paper 195.

 7 Data on interest rates on U.S. Treasury bonds is available from the Federal Reserve Board at http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/.

 8 Chirinko, R.S., 1993. “Business Fixed Investment Spending: A Critical Survey of Modeling Strategies, Empirical Results, and Policy Implications,” Journal of Economic Literature (December): 1875-1911.

 Related Article

 Business Cycle Drivers  by derryl

Share this Econintersect Article:
  • Print
  • Digg
  • Facebook
  • Yahoo! Buzz
  • Twitter
  • Google Bookmarks
  • LinkedIn
  • Wikio
  • email
  • RSS
This entry was posted in Great Debate©, Studies and tagged , , , , , . Bookmark the permalink.










Make a Comment

Econintersect wants your comments, data and opinion on the articles posted.  As the internet is a "war zone" of trolls, hackers and spammers - Econintersect must balance its defences against ease of commenting.  We have joined with Livefyre to manage our comment streams.

To comment, just click the "Sign In" button at the top-left corner of the comment box below. You can create a commenting account using your favorite social network such as Twitter, Facebook, Google+, LinkedIn or Open ID - or open a Livefyre account using your email address.





7 Responses to The Great Debate© – Can Austerity Produce Recovery from The Great Recession?

  1. Sunil Chandra says:

    The tragedy about counting unemployment in percentages is that it hides the human misery behind bland numbers. Therefore, to give it a perspective, can we say that the country has over 14,000,000 unemployed persons. We may also add an equal number of underemployed and those earning less than 50% of what they were earning in 2007-08. Finally, we have the big picture- around 30,000,000 US citizens are facing economic desolation.

    This certainly calls for a response that directly creates jobs and incomes for these people. This is not the time to go for round-about responses where one increases corporate incomes and then hopes for the trickle down effect. These people do not need trickles; they need jobs that will restore their self respect and allow them to survive this economic recession.

    Lastly, the country needs to shed inhibitions about being a “socialist” type of state. Extreme situations call for extreme responses and there is no shame in becoming a welfare state in order to to tide over the current problems.

  2. RagingDebate says:

    I remember our conversation a couple of years ago Mr. Baker when I was first establishing Raging Debate and we discussed pyschographic data segmentation McKinsey was doing for the Obama campaign.

    A WPO program in 2008 as I advised President Bush in the construction of energy production would have been the best solution. Also advised in May of 2008 was to firesale the TBTF banks. The problem Mr. Baker is the stimulus is either wasted on pork projects, bolstering revenue for public unions, taken as bonuses at TBTF where executives continue strip-mining the company or in emerging markets growing investments for insiders as the domestic economy shatters.

    Regulations are aimed at start-ups and early stage companies to lock out competition. Since the 1980′s almost ALL job growth has come from start-ups. Probably more fundamentally important is that bankers run the country. Bankers make loans. The money-multiplier is negative as John Lounsbury has repeatedly reported on. So to apply stimulus toward fiscal policy with bankers that are not familiar with running a Save and Invest economy is folly. The painful route of Andrew Mellon and the liquidation will ensue. Of course, this is highly deflationary and I do not cheerlead pain.

    These are all very serious malinvestments that I have mentioned that have seriously eroded investor confidence. The playing field must be leveled and government does not use a scalpal, everything looks like a nail to them.

    Bankers can recruit a B team of knowledgeable Save and Invest economists to aid policy-makers (that are clueless after 40 years of relying on the Fed), create the scalpal to determine the segmentation of underutilized value and then stimulus measues can be much smaller in scope but I do agree with your general premise about them. However, first things first. Until the regulatory environment changes for a level playing field nothing but dollar devaluation, cuts (already happening in Medicare) and direct and indirect taxation shall continue. The pain of no growth will force the investment community into reform efforts. History rythmes and I will place my money were my mouth is.

    Sunil, the United States has plenty of natural resources. Americans can make sure nobody starves but wages and benefits for the public sector is near double the private sector and corporate welfare is destroying capital formation. We already tried socialism, that is why the United States has at least $60 T in unfunded liabilities.

  3. Roger Erickson says:

    This whole discussion is presented in terms that are far too narrow for the subject and context at hand. Shewhart’s old dictum applies, “Without context, data is meaningless.”

    The deeper issue is that there is a clear ontology that is part & parcel of all economic development. This is best exemplified by considering other ontologies. Can you imagine how obtuse it is, when describing human ontology, including 9months pre-birth & years after, to dryly argue that “public investment” or “socialistic lack of competition” are or aren’t useful? They are simply tools in the toolkit of a growing nation, or of a growing physiology! All that matters is the choreographed artistry of inventive application. We can’t get back to making a more perfect union until we quit arguing about which tools can & can’t be used, and get back to a focus on HOW & WHEN to use them all in any & all permutations, as context demands. Enough already!

    This country has a real-goods maintenance budget to manage, and an adaptive rate budget to also manage. Any and all discussions of nominal currency are simply that – entirely nominal, and about internal bookkeeping, not REAL budgets. Ask our Pentagon staff what they think about the relative importance of Fx rates vs net capabilities. Their ultimate answer is that we persist or perish together, not just by keeping score among competing subunits.

    ps: Arguments for “growth through austerity” are especially ludicrous coming from Goldman Sachs employees who actually received personal bonuses for destroying national wealth and undermining national capabilities – thereby adding insult to civic injury. Instead, charges of sedition against most Wall St. bankers could well be in order, if more attention was directed to reviewing real operations.

  4. Roger Erickson says:

    ps: apologies, just realized a typo; my comment should say “ontogeny”, not ontology;
    my bad

  5. Pingback: Tax Law Stimulus | Global Economic Intersection

  6. derryl says:

    Can austerity generate prosperity? Absolutely. All it takes is for the austere to revolt against the prosperous and steal all their wealth. Bingo. Prosperity. It lasts about 15 minutes but during that brief shining moment it feels like you won. Congratulations.

    Prosperity is a pie that need continuous rebaking. You wanna bake the pie? And then give it over to those who have a “right” to eat pie that they haven’t earned?

    Economics sucks. It’s hard. Better to do finance. Nobody asks if you “earned” your money, not like on the street where a 7 bucks an hour minimum wage is discussed as “excessive”. In finance you make 6 figures as a birthright. You sell loser investments so you “deserve” $300k, $1 million per annum. The streetsweeper leaves us with clean streets, for $14K per annum. You leave us with investment losses year after year. You “deserve” a 6 figure salary and “bonuses”. When you lose our money where is our payback?

    Newsflash. There is no payback. Thieves keep all the money they steal. Long ago in another world that we used to live in, we took all our money back and put the thieves in jail. Nowadays we put the thieves in charge of the United States Treasury Department and we let them give all our national money away to their thief buddies.

    I’m not a thief. I’ll never be rich. I’m not willing to give away enough of my heart to play the rich game. Because the thieves have nothing they can corrupt me with I am free to speak the truth. I can call them “thieves”, which is what they are. The tragedy is that people who read this and know I speak the truth will not try to do anything about it.

    Maybe I’m wrong. Maybe God’s plan for the world is to let the thieves reign during my unfortunate time upon this rock. Maybe I live in God’s Age of Thieves. That I live in an age of thieves is certain. They are busy stealing the world as I write these lines. The question is, Do we stop them and prosecute them? Or do we live in the world of thieves where they reign supreme?

  7. “There has been a considerable effort to tout the merits of fiscal austerity as a route to restoring growth. This argument has been put forward in direct opposition to arguments for increased stimulus for boosting the economy. While there may be a case that lower deficits can foster growth under some circumstances, the evidence presented in the Broadbent and Daly paper does not suggest that a movement toward lower deficits in the current economic situation in the United States would be expansionary.”

    There are two situations – one where an economic event occurred and you need to get through the crisis. In this event, spending your way through the crisis is the correct path.

    But i suggest the USA is in the second situation – the economy is miss-geared to the underlying dynamics (high debt, baby boomers coming to roost, globalization). spending your way through this event without re-gearing is dangerous.

    This may not be a situation where the choice is black or white – spend or eliminate deficits. i vote for door #3 – spend, re-gear, and put the economy back on a path to fiscal responsibility.